Bruce Cooil, Timothy L. Keiningham, Lerzan Aksoy, & Michael Hsu A Longitudinal Analysis of Customer Satisfaction and Share of Wallet: Investigating the Moderating Effect of Customer Characteristics Customer loyalty is an important strategic objective for all managers. Research has investigated the relationship between customer satisfaction and loyalty in various contexts. However, these predominantly cross-sectional studies have focused on customer retention as the primary measure of loyalty. There has been little investigation into the impact on share of wallet.
Using data from the Canadian banking industry, this research aims to (1) provide the first longitudinal examination of the impact of changes in customer satisfaction on changes in share of wallet and (2) determine the moderating effects of customer age, income, education, expertise, and length of relationship. Data from 4319 households using 12,249 observations over a five-year period indicate a positive relationship between changes in satisfaction and share of wallet. In particular, the initial satisfaction level and the conditional percentile of change in satisfaction significantly correspond to changes in share of wallet.
Two variables, income and length of the relationship, negatively moderate this relationship. Other demographic and situational characteristics have no impact. ustomer loyalty is an important strategic objective of managers around the world. A worldwide survey of chief executive officers conducted by the Conference Board (Bell 2002) found that customer loyalty and retention was the most important challenge that chief executive officers believed they faced. Despite managers’ emphasis on loyalty, however, brand loyalty is widely reported to be declining (Chancy 2001).
Compared with the more exclusive loyalty of the past, consumers increasingly hold polygamous loyalty to brands (Bennett and RundleThiele 2005; Rust, Lemon, and Zeithaml 2004; Uncles, Dowling, and Hammond 2003; Uncles, Ehrenberg, and Hammond 1995). As a result, customers are increasingly dividing their purchases among multiple brands in a category. For example, Kraft Foods defines a loyal customer as someone who purchases 70% or more of the same brand within a category over three years. On the basis of this benchmark, 30 years ago, 40% of Kraft’s customers would C
Bruce Cooil is Professor of Management, Owen Graduate School of Management, Vanderbilt University (e-mail: bruce. [email protected] vanderbilt. edu). Timothy L. Keiningham is Senior Vice President and Head of Consulting, Ipsos Loyalty (e-mail: tim. [email protected] com). Lerzan Aksoy is Assistant Professor of Marketing, College of Administrative Sciences and Economics, Koc University (e-mail: [email protected] edu. tr). Michael Hsu is Associate Vice President, Ipsos Reid (e-mail: michael. [email protected] com). Bruce Cooil acknowledges support from the Dean’s Fund for Faculty Research, Owen Graduate School of Management, Vanderbilt University.
To read and contribute to reader and author dialogue on JM, visit http://www. marketingpower. com/jmblog. have been classified as loyal. Today, that number is closer to 15% (Zabin and Brebach 2004). Jones and Sasser (1995, p. 94) assert that “the ultimate measure of loyalty … is share of purchases in the category” (i. e. , share of wallet). Although this may be an overstatement, because share of wallet is not as forward looking as other measures of loyalty (Oliver 1999), it is frequently used by researchers to operationalize loyalty behavior (e. . , Bowman, Farley, and Schmittlein 2000; Bowman and Narayandas 2004; Brody and Cunningham 1968; Cunningham 1956, 1961; Wind 1970). In an effort to increase customers’ share of spending with a brand, managers have focused on improving customers’ level of satisfaction. Rust (2002) explains the logic as follows: “Customer satisfaction and delight have a tremendous impact on customer retention and customer loyalty, and the result of that is that you keep customers around longer, and you also get a higher share of their wallet. Early research supports the suggested link between satisfaction and share of wallet (Baumann, Burton, and Elliott 2005; Bowman and Narayandas 2004; Keiningham, Perkins-Munn, et al. 2005; Keiningham, Perkins-Munn, and Evans 2003; Perkins-Munn et al. 2005; Silvestro and Cross 2000). In managerial terms, the relevance of such a linkage is that changes in customers’ levels of satisfaction are presumed to correspond to changes in customers’ share-ofwallet allocations.
Yet despite the widespread recognition that “marketers should examine changes in customer satisfaction over time” when evaluating satisfaction’s impact on customer behavior (Bolton, Lemon, and Verhoef 2004, p. 277), research examining the relationship between satisfaction and share of wallet has disregarded temporal effects and has relied almost exclusively on cross-sectional (single 67 Journal of Marketing Vol. 71 (January 2007), 67–83 © 2007, American Marketing Association ISSN: 0022-2429 (print), 1547-7185 (electronic) point in time) data.
Therefore, estimations of the impact of changes in satisfaction on share of wallet over time cannot comfortably be made, nor can inferences of causality. In addition, research has found that the nature of the relationship between satisfaction and customer behavior (repurchase intention and retention) is moderated by the differentiating characteristics of various customer groups (e. g. , age, sex, education) (Mittal and Kamakura 2001). Currently, however, no research exists that examines the effect of customer characteristics on the relationship between satisfaction and share of wallet. The objectives of this article are to (1) provide the first longitudinal examination of the association between customer satisfaction and customers’ share of spending (share of wallet) and (2) test the moderating effect of customer characteristics on this relationship. The data used to investigate the proposed relationships consist of 4319 Canadian households whose banking relationships were tracked for a minimum of three years. Share of wallet represents the percentage of the business that households allocate to various financial institutions for different banking products/services across all financial institutions that the household uses.
Theoretical Background Customer Satisfaction and Share of Wallet Customer satisfaction has traditionally been regarded as a fundamental determinant of long-term consumer behavior (Oliver 1980; Yi 1990). Much of the research on customer satisfaction and customers’ actual behavior has focused on the relationship between satisfaction and retention. This emphasis is largely the result of early research, which identified customer retention as a key driver of firm profitability (Reichheld 1993, 1996; Reichheld and Kenny 1991; Reichheld, Markey, and Hopton 2000; Reichheld and Sasser 1990).
Capraro, Broniarczyk, and Srivastava (2003, p. 164) observe that “today, most firm’s programs to control customer defections center heavily on the management of customer satisfaction. ” Research appears to support this approach. Many studies have linked customer satisfaction to purchase behavior (Anderson and Sullivan 1993; Bolton 1998; Jones and Sasser 1995; LaBarbera and Mazursky 1983; Loveman 1998; Mittal and Kamakura 2001; Newman and Werbel 1973; Rust and Zahorik 1993; Sambandam and Lord 1995). Furthermore, the majority of researchers 1This study examines share of wallet rather than retention or loyalty.
Indeed, there is a relationship among share of wallet, retention, and loyalty, but they are distinct constructs in the literature. Simplistically, definitions for the three can be understood as follows: Share of wallet is the percentage of money a customer allocates in a category that is assigned to a specific firm. Retention is a measure of the continuance of a relationship with a firm (i. e. , it can be only 0 or 1). Loyalty is “a deeply held commitment to rebuy or re-patronize a preferred product/service in the future” (Oliver 1999, p. 34).
As such, loyalty is a multidimensional construct. There is no universally accepted definition of loyalty in the literature, but it is typically believed to consist of an attitudinal and a behavioral component (Uncles, Dowling, and Hammond 2003). attempting to conceptualize and operationalize the chain of effects from satisfaction to profits have proposed models that link satisfaction to retention and retention to profits (e. g. , Anderson and Mittal 2000; Heskett et al. 1994; Rust, Zahorik, and Keiningham 1995; Zeithaml, Berry, and Parasuraman 1996).
Recently, however, researchers and managers have begun to question fundamental aspects of the relationship between customer retention and firm profitability (Carroll 1991–1992; Carroll and Rose 1993; Coyles and Gokey 2002; Gupta and Lehmann 2005; Keiningham, Vavra, et al. 2005; Reinartz and Kumar 2000, 2002). One such question pertains to how loyalty is conceptualized and measured. Researchers and managers have become increasingly interested in consumers’ share of spending as a behavioral measure of customer loyalty (Keiningham, Aksoy, et al. 005; Uncles, Dowling, and Hammond 2003). For example, Zeithaml (2000, 76) notes a “growing popularity of the concept of ‘share of wallet. ’” Research conducted by McKinsey & Company also supports this change in focus from retention to share of wallet, and Coyles and Gokey (2002) find that efforts to improve customers’ share of spending and customer retention can add as much as ten times greater value to a company than focusing on retention alone. Marketing theory and empirical research lend credibility to this shift in focus.
Zeithaml (2000) proposes a model in which customer retention leads to firm profits in one of four ways: (1) lowering costs to service customers, (2) the ability to charge premium prices, (3) word of mouth, and (4) increased volume of purchase (i. e. , increased share of wallet). However, Reinartz and Kumar (2000, 2002) find that customer retention does not result in loyal customers costing less to serve, paying higher prices for the same bundle of services, or marketing the company through word of mouth.
Therefore, this implies that the primary path from retention to firm profitability in Zeithaml’s (2000) proposed model is through increased share of wallet. Rust, Lemon, and Zeithaml (2004) also note that the way researchers have treated customer retention does not accurately portray customers’ actual behavior patterns, observing that researchers frequently treat customers who defect as “lost for good. ” They argue that a “more realistic scenario” is that customers may leave and return and be either serially monogamous or polygamous in terms of the number of firms with which they conduct business in the category.
This treatment of retention closely mirrors the concept of share of wallet. The observation that consumers continuously leave and return to a product, service, or institution over a period of time is consistent with commonly used measures of share of category spending (Stern and Hammond 2004). Typically, consumers’ share of spending across a broad range of business sectors is measured as the share of purchases customers provide to a particular brand in the category over a fixed period (Cunningham 1956; Jones and Sasser 1995; Zabin and Brebach 2004).
Retention and share of wallet, though not identical, are closely related. The finding that consumers engage in serially monogamous or polygamous relationships with companies unequivocally implies a close link between retention/ repurchase and share of category spending (share of wallet). 68 / Journal of Marketing, January 2007 Therefore, it is reasonable to expect that satisfaction and share of wallet are positively associated. This is supported by current marketing theory.
In their model of customer asset management of services, Bolton, Lemon, and Verhoef (2004) propose that customer satisfaction has a positive influence on cross-buying, a proposition supported by several researchers (Anderson and Sullivan 1993; Cronin and Taylor 1992; Parasuraman, Zeithaml, and Berry 1988; Verhoef, Franses, and Hoekstra 2001; Zeithaml, Berry, and Parasuraman 1996); in other words, customer satisfaction is related to customers’ allocation of a greater share of their spending to the firm.
In addition, Bowman and Narayandas (2004) and Keiningham, Aksoy, and colleagues (2005) conceptualize and operationalize the satisfaction–profit chain that Anderson and Mittal (2000) propose, which links satisfaction to retention as (1) satisfaction to (2) share of wallet to (3) revenue to (4) profit.
The substitution of share of wallet for retention in the satisfaction–profit chain is further supported by Perkins-Munn and colleagues’ (2005) research, which shows that the two constructs are highly correlated and that the relationship between attribute satisfaction and retention is similar to the relationship between attribute satisfaction and share of wallet. Empirical research appears to confirm the link between satisfaction and share of wallet across various industries. Researchers have found a positive relationship between satisfaction and share of wallet for the fleet trucking (PerkinsMunn et al. 005), pharmaceutical (Perkins-Munn et al. 2005), institutional securities (Keiningham, Perkins-Munn, et al. 2005), retail banking (Baumann, Burton, and Elliott 2005), processed metals (Bowman and Narayandas 2004), and grocery retailing (Magi 2003; Silvestro and Cross 2000) industries. To date, however, research into the relationship between satisfaction and share of wallet has relied exclusively on cross-sectional data. Bernhardt, Donthu, and Kennett (2000, p. 164) also assert that “the true impact of satisfaction on performance measures is not apparent when taking a cross-sectional approach.
A longitudinal view seems to be necessary. ” Although longitudinal examinations of the effect of customer satisfaction on other performance measures have found a positive relationship to customer retention (Bolton 1998), firm revenues (Bernhardt, Donthu, and Kennett 2000; Gruca and Rego 2005; Ittner and Larcker 1998), and shareholder value (Anderson, Fornell, and Mazvancheryl 2004; Fornell 2003; Fornell et al. 2006; Gruca and Rego 2005), the impact on share of wallet currently remains elusive.
Given the findings of cross-sectional studies regarding satisfaction and share of wallet and the findings of longitudinal studies regarding the relationship between satisfaction and other performance variables, we hypothesize the following (see Figure 1): H1: The relationship between a change in customer satisfaction and a contemporaneous change in current share of wallet is positive. The effects of customer satisfaction on customer behavior and business results are widely believed to be nonlinear and asymmetric (Anderson and Mittal 2000; Coyne 1989; Jones and Sasser 1995; Keiningham and Vavra 2001; Oliva, Oliver, and MacMillan 1992).
The nonlinearity and asymmetry of the relationship between customer satisfaction and repurchase intentions has been confirmed in several studies (Bloemer, Kasper, and Lemmink 1990; DeSarbo et al. 1994; Mittal and Baldasare 1996; Mittal et al. 1998; Oliver, Rust, and Varki 1997). Mittal and Kamakura (2001) find that this nonlinear and asymmetric relationship also holds true for repurchase. Likewise, Anderson (1998) finds that FIGURE 1 The Model and Hypotheses Customer Satisfaction and Share of Wallet / 69 he relationship between customer satisfaction and word of mouth is asymmetric and nonlinear. Similarly, recent research on customer loyalty and share of wallet has uncovered nonlinear relationships. Austin and Singh (2005) report curvilinear effects of the determinants of loyalty intentions. Keiningham, Perkins-Munn, and Evans (2003) and Bowman and Narayandas (2004) find a positive, nonlinear relationship between satisfaction and share of wallet. These findings can be explained, in part, through research on expectations.
Satisfaction is “strongly influenced by customer expectations” (Rust, Zahorik, and Keiningham 1994, p. 42). Researchers have found multiple expectation thresholds. As expectations converge with respect to what is expected to happen, what should happen, and what would happen in the “ideal” situation, firms achieve greater competitive positioning (Boulding et al. 1993; Miller 1977; Swan and Combs 1976). This implies that there are expectation thresholds based on the consistency of delivery that must be met for customers to consider a firm.
The research on expectations interlocks well with the research of Kano (1997), Oliver (1997), and Anderson and Mittal (2000) regarding satisfaction. In particular, these researchers propose that there are thresholds with regard to performance of a particular attribute on customer satisfaction. Furthermore, Anderson and Mittal (2000) and Keiningham and Vavra (2001) propose that similar thresholds exist with regard to changes in customer satisfaction and changes in customer behavior (i. e. unless satisfaction levels reach a certain threshold, changes in satisfaction will have little impact on customer behavior). Early findings support such a relationship. In a longitudinal examination of customer satisfaction and sales performance for two retailers, Keiningham and colleagues (2006) find that the relationship between changes in satisfaction and changes in sales is determined, in part, by customers’ baseline levels of satisfaction. As a result, we do not expect that changes in share of wallet are linearly related to changes in satisfaction (as measured directly on a Likert scale).
In particular, we expect that the baseline level of satisfaction affects the relationship between changes in satisfaction and changes in share of wallet. Furthermore, the effect of satisfaction on share of wallet has been shown to differ by customer type (segment). Keiningham, Perkins-Munn, and Evans (2003) study the relationship between satisfaction and share of wallet, examining the impact of different organizational buyer groups. Their findings show that the relationship between satisfaction and share of wallet varies considerably by buyer group and that the relationship is nonlinear.
Similarly, Baumann, Burton, and Elliott (2005) find that customer characteristics affect share-of-wallet allocations in retail banking; in particular, they find that age is positively associated with share of wallet. Thus: H2: The positive relationship between changes in share of wallet and changes in satisfaction (a) depends on the baseline satisfaction level and (b) differs by customer segment. Moderators in the Satisfaction–Share-of-Wallet Relationship There is a stream of research that consistently finds variations in satisfaction ratings based on numerous customer characteristics (e. . , Bryant and Cha 1996; Mittal and Kamakura 2001; Peterson and Wilson 1992; Ross et al. 1999; Varki and Rust 1997; Venn and Fone 2005). Recently, it has been found that customer characteristics moderate the relationship between satisfaction and behavioral outcomes (Baumann, Burton, and Elliott 2005; Magi 2003; Mittal and Kamakura 2001; Homburg and Giering 2001; Homburg, Giering, and Menon 2003; Keiningham, Perkins-Munn, and Evans 2003). However, such analyses should not be limited solely to traditional demographic variables (e. . , age, education, income). Situational characteristics, such as price orientation (Kim, Srinivasan, and Wilcox 1999; Magi 2003), tenure of relationship (Homburg, Giering, and Menon 2003), expertise (Andreassen and Lindestad 1998; Chiou, Droge, and Hanvanich 2002), involvement (Bloemer and Kasper 1995; Bloemer and Odekerken-Schroder 2002; Homburg and Giering 2001), and purchase volume (Magi 2003), have all been found to influence the relationship between satisfaction and customer behavior.
In this study, we investigate three demographic (age, income, and education) and two situational (expertise and tenure) variables. We specifically selected these variables because a stream of prior research has shown each to affect customer loyalty. A brief discussion of each of these potential moderators and their corresponding effects follows. Age. Age moderates the relationship between satisfaction and loyalty (Baumann, Burton, and Elliott 2005; Homburg and Giering 2001).
In particular, older consumers are more loyal to a particular brand than younger consumers in the automotive (Homburg and Giering 2001; LambertPandraud, Laurent, and Lapersonne 2005) and banking (Baumann, Burton, and Elliott 2005) industries. However, the expected relationship between age and loyalty has not been universal. A large-scale study by American Association of Retired Persons finds that older consumers are just as likely to switch brands or experiment with alternative brands as are younger consumers (Moos 2004).
Mittal and Kamakura (2001) find that the relationship between satisfaction scores and repurchase behavior for cars is stronger for younger than for older consumers. Age has also been negatively linked to customer share (East et al. 1995; East et al. 2000). East and colleagues (2000) propose that older consumers have more free time, are able to spend more time shopping, and thus are able to shop at multiple stores. Some studies have found that the middleage segment is the most loyal.
Wright and Sparks (1999) find high loyalty in the 35–44 age group, and McGoldrick and Andre (1997) state that loyal shoppers are more likely to be the middle-age group. Conversely, Magi (2003) finds that age does not moderate the relationship between satisfaction and loyalty for grocery consumers. Despite contradictory findings regarding the impact of age, studies in the industry under examination, banking (see 70 / Journal of Marketing, January 2007 Baumann, Burton, and Elliott 2005), suggest a positive impact.
In addition, Lambert-Pandraud, Laurent, and Lapersonne (2005) apply four age-related theoretical perspectives to explain why age and loyalty should be positively associated: biological aging, cognitive decline, socioemotional selectivity, and change aversion. Applying this to the banking industry context, (1) biological aging suggests that increasing physical impairment associated with age reduces the number of banks customers use; (2) cognitive decline suggests that because of the reduced ability to evaluate complex options, older customers reduce their consideration set (i. e. number of banking relationships); (3) socioemotional selectivity suggests that older customers place a greater emphasis on feelings and emotions, and therefore, in the case of retail banking, older customers should be more interested in the relationship experience; and (4) change aversion is expected to increase with age, and therefore, in the context of banking, the risk older customers associate with switching banks is likely to be considered greater than it is for younger customers. Thus: H3: The impact of a change in customer satisfaction on change in share of wallet increases with the consumer’s age. ing brand loyalty.
Sharir argues that both patterns are likely to be relevant, but it is impossible to know a priori. However, by its very nature, increased wealth provides greater opportunities to obtain a greater variety of financial products. Economic barriers affect the ability of lowerincome and moderate-income households to hold various financial products (Barr 2004). In addition, customers’ financial needs change as affluence increases (Asher 2001). Furthermore, several banking institutions compete primarily for high-income customers (Bielski 2004), whereas retail banking services are designed to have appeal across income levels.
Therefore, given that higher-income people have greater opportunities for more diverse financial products, that there is greater competition for their business, and that selection of financial products has a direct income-relevant component that may offset time costs, we hypothesize the following: H4: The impact of a change in customer satisfaction on change in share of wallet decreases with the consumer’s income level. Income. A large body of research suggests that income is negatively linked to customer loyalty (Crask and Reynolds 1978; Korgaonkar, Lund, and Price 1985; Zeithaml 1985).
Because higher-income consumers have fewer shopping restrictions, they are believed to exhibit less loyalty than low-income consumers (Sharir 1974; Zeithaml 1985). In addition, Homburg and Giering (2001) find that income is an important, negative moderator of the satisfaction–loyalty relationship. However, findings regarding the relationship between income and customer behavior are not unanimous. In a study of online services, Keaveney and Parthasarathy (2001) find that online service “continuers” have higher average income levels than switchers.
In the case of automobiles, Evans (1962) finds that fewer dealers are visited as incomes rise. The discrepancy may be explained, in part, by customers’ perceptions of the cost of time (Farley 1964a). A high-income consumer is believed to hold a higher valuation of time (Frank, Green, and Sieber 1967; Goldman and Johansson 1978; Marmorstein, Grewal, and Fishe 1992; Murthi and Srinivasan 1999). Therefore, a higher-income consumer may be more willing to trade off time in favor of a choice on the basis of limited evaluation, meaning that a consumer with a higher income may be less likely to evaluate in certain product categories.
Indeed, there is empirical evidence that shows that income is negatively related to external search (Beatty and Smith 1987; Udell 1966). Sharir (1974) argues that as households’ cost of time increases, it affects customers’ behavior in one of two ways: (1) Customers reduce their time spent buying goods (e. g. , in search, deliberation, decision making), thus reducing consideration set size and increasing brand loyalty, or (2) customers avoid searching for information and deliberating on the brands to be bought, their sequence, and their shares and may buy at random (as with impulse buying), thus decreas- Education.
Prior research tends to show that higher levels of education are associated with lower levels of customer loyalty (Chance and French 1972; Mittal and Kamakura 2001; Murphy 1978). People with higher education levels are believed to engage in greater information gathering and usage before decision making (Capon and Burke 1980). As a result, more highly educated consumers have greater awareness of alternatives. Furthermore, people with higher levels of education tend to be associated with higher income levels (Farley1964b), and as we noted previously, higher income can be associated with lower levels of loyalty.
A notable exception has been found with regard to online services. As with the relationship between income and loyalty, however, Keaveney and Parthasarathy (2001) find that online service continuers have higher average education levels than switchers. Given that most previous studies have shown that higher levels of education are associated with lower levels of loyalty, we hypothesize the following: H5: The impact of a change in customer satisfaction on change in share of wallet decreases as the consumer becomes more educated. Expertise.
Previous research shows that consumer expertise can influence customer loyalty (Bell, Auh, and Smalley 2005; Maheswaran 1994; Mitchell and Dacin 1996). East (1992) argues that higher levels of knowledge lead to lower levels of customer loyalty because knowledge provides customers with information about competing alternatives. Moorthy, Ratchford, and Talukdar (1997) argue that as customers gain experience, they use more attributes and more attribute levels to differentiate among offerings. This is likely due to the difference between novices’ and experts’ associative knowledge networks.
Experts have more developed and complex cognitive structures than novices (Alba and Hutchinson 1987). As a result, experts may be more likely to be receptive to competitive offerings. Because Customer Satisfaction and Share of Wallet / 71 novices find it more difficult to make comparisons, they perceive greater risk in decision making (Heilman, Bowman, and Wright 2000) and thus prefer to stay more loyal. Capraro, Broniarczyk, and Srivastava (2003) conducted tests to determine whether knowledge mediates or moderates the satisfaction–customer retention linkage.
However, their research supports neither mediation nor moderation, instead concluding that both knowledge and satisfaction independently influence customer defections. Given the preceding controversy, we propose the following alternate hypotheses: H6a: Higher levels of expertise are negatively associated with a change in share of wallet, after the effects of other moderators are adjusted for. H6b: The impact of a change in customer satisfaction on change in share of wallet decreases with higher levels of consumer expertise. Length of relationship.
Firm–customer relationships are evolutionary, time-adjusted associations. With repeated interactions, firms and customers develop bonds, and the reinforcements from satisfactory interactions help build customer loyalty (Anderson and Sullivan 1993; Anderson and Weitz 1989). Customers with positive experiences over time are less likely to defect and are more forgiving (Anderson and Sullivan 1993). As a result, customers’ judgments of recent exchange outcomes are influenced by the cumulative effect of long-term experiences with the product, service, or institution (Kalwani and Narayandas 1995).
Thus, in the case of relationships that have aged, shifts in satisfaction have a weaker impact on loyalty. In addition, with time and effort investments, switching costs tend to increase, making it more difficult to switch. Prior research tends to support this finding. Homburg, Giering, and Menon (2003) find that the longer the relationship between the buyer and the seller, the weaker the relationship is between customer satisfaction and customer loyalty.
Thus: H7: The impact of a change in customer satisfaction on change in share of wallet decreases with an increase in the length of relationship between the consumer and the company. 40% for three years, 23% for four years, and 21% for five years). For these households, there are 12,249 observations. Among the observed changes in share of wallet at each institution, 34% involve only “money-in” transactions (e. g. , checking accounts, savings, investments), 1% involve only “money-out” transactions (e. g. , loans, lines of credit, credit cards), and 65% involve both types of business (see Table 1).
Share of wallet represents the percentage of total business, in dollars, conducted with the financial institution (e. g. , total dollars with the institution divided by total dollars across all financial institutions; i. e. , customers’ relationships with all bank entities are recorded). We measured overall satisfaction for the institution or institutions (up to three) that the respondent believed to be primary. We measured satisfaction on a four-point semantic scale (4 = “extremely satisfied,” 3 = “somewhat satisfied,” 2 = “somewhat dissatisfied,” 1 = “extremely dissatisfied”).
In addition, we included several customer characteristics in the study: age, income, education, length of relationship, and expertise. We did not measure expertise directly. Instead, we asked respondents if they used various professional financial advisory services. The use of such professional advisors could logically indicate (1) a degree of sophistication on the part of the customer and (2) direct access to subject-matter experts. It is reasonable to presume that use of financial advisors indicates a customer’s desire to better manage his or her financial assets.
We recognize that a counterargument can be made about the use of a financial advisor. It might simply be a proxy for the respondent’s lack of expertise. Although we believe that the former explanation is more probable than the latter, under either scenario, the use of a financial advisor would be construed as a proxy for expertise, the former being a positive association and the latter being a negative one. However, the variable we use here indicates only whether a customer used advisory services and provides
TABLE 1 Broad Breakdown of Types of Money-In and Money-Out Products Under Analysis Money-In Products •Checking and savings accounts •Guaranteed investment certificatesa •Bondsb •Stocksb •Mutual fundsb •(Pensions are excluded) Money-Out Products •Credit cards •Mortgages •Personal loans •Lines of credit (secured, unsecured) aThese Methodology Data Collection and Measurement The data we used in this study were collected as part of an ongoing national panel study of Canadian bank customers for the years 2000–2004.
More than 10,000 Canadian households are surveyed annually; information is gathered on all financial products (deposit, loan, and investment) and all financial institutions that each household used. Respondents are selected from across Canada, with representative sampling designed to mirror the geodemographic profile of Canadian households. When possible, respondents are tracked for multiple years. For the purpose of this investigation, we used only households that responded in two or more consecutive years.
This study provides sufficient information on 4319 households to test the seven hypotheses (16% for two years, 72 / Journal of Marketing, January 2007 are deposit investment securities sold by Canadian banks and trust companies. They are often bought for retirement plans because they provide a low-risk fixed rate of return. The principal is at risk only if the bank defaults. bThere is no Glass-Stegall equivalent in Canada to separate commercial banking from investment banking/securities brokerage.
TABLE 2 Descriptive Statistics for 4319 Households and First Follow-Up Variable Type Dependent TB_SOW change (%) Satisfaction Initial (category) Moderators Age (years) Income ($1,000 category) Education (category) Tenure (years) Business Activity TB_SOW (%) Money-in ($1,000) Money-out ($1,000) Money-out/TB (%) 50. 139. 1 36. 8 32. 37 247. 2 55. 1 47 11 8. 3 . 00 0 48. 46. 9 9. 6 0 90. 156. 5 62. 5 100. 53 – – 5. 8 15 – – 1. 6 42 25–30 9–13 years 5. 0 53 45–55 Some college 7. 0 65 70–100 Certificate/diploma 7. – – Satisfied Extremely satisfied Extremely satisfied 0 28 –8 0 7 Variable M SD First Quartile Mdn Third Quartile Notes: Satisfaction decreased for 15% of first follow-ups (14% of all follow-ups); initial satisfaction was at either “satisfied” or “extremely satisfied” and did not move out of this range for 67% of first follow-ups (69% of all follow-ups). Additional information on other household characteristics at baseline: 78% sought professional advice, and 32% had only money-in accounts.
TB_SOW = total business share of wallet. only limited information about customer expertise. Table 2 provides descriptive statistics on the 4319 households used in this study. other households that started at the same level of satisfaction. Covariates for Latent Class Preliminary latent class analyses showed that covariates representing the type and dollar level of household transactions from the last period were more important than household demographics for predicting total business share of wallet.
Thus, we used the following covariates: the last period’s values of (1) total business share of wallet (TB_SOWt – 1), (2) total dollar amount of money-in accounts (MIt – 1), (3) total dollar amount for money-out transactions (see Table 1) (money-out: MOt – 1), and (4) the proportion of total business in money-out transactions ([MO/TB]t – 1). Model Development We used a two-level latent class regression model to predict annual changes in the share of wallet per household with each financial institution.
This model allows for household random effects, so that even though the data across households are assumed to be independent, the observations per household are independent only after conditioning on this random effect. This is a natural extension of the conventional approach, in that the probability of belonging to a given latent class is still a logistic function of covariates, but these covariates now include the household random effect (Vermunt 2003). This random effect has a mean of zero and a variance that is specific to the latent class. We estimated parameters with maximum likelihood estimation.
The mathematical details appear in the Appendix. Lenk and DeSarbo (2000) also use random effects in a latent class framework, though their approach is mathematically and conceptually different. To represent the change in satisfaction, we tested several candidate predictors, including the conditional percentile of change given the initial satisfaction level, the ordinal change in Likert scale units, indicators for any increase and any decrease, and indicators for whether a customer moved from a satisfied (Levels 3 or 4) to a dissatisfied (Levels 1 or 2) state and for any change in the other direction.
Exploratory best-subsets analyses and preliminary restricted latent class model analysis indicated that the conditional percentile of change in satisfaction was the most important predictor and that other measures of change in satisfaction did not provide significant incremental value. The conditional percentile of change in satisfaction is the change in household satisfaction (from the original Likert scale) expressed as a conditional percentile relative to all Predictors for Change in Total Business Share of Wallet
We used these same four variables as candidate predictors for total business share of wallet in the regression equations, along with an indicator for whether all business was in money-in transactions. Other candidate predictors included all the information about the moderating variables we proposed in H3–H7: household income, the length of time households used the services of the institution (tenure), whether they used financial advisory services (advisory), and the age and education of the head of the household who was taking the survey.
We expressed household income and all education variables as percentiles relative to the sample. We measured brand effects by including indicators for the financial institution. Model Selection Initially, we included all information about transactions and household characteristics as predictors, along with the indicators for financial institution. We found the optimal number of latent classes by minimizing the Bayesian informaCustomer Satisfaction and Share of Wallet / 73 ion criterion (BIC; Schwarz 1978; see also Bozdogan 1987). We chose BIC because it is a consistent criterion under general conditions (Rao and Wu 1989; Woodroofe 1982), and there is substantial theoretical and empirical work that suggests that it is effective in finding a good scientific model in many settings (Rust et al. 1995; Steyerberg et al. 2001), including latent class analyses (Biernacki and Govaert 1999; Dias 2004).
We then modified the model by backward stepwise elimination of predictors and simplification across latent classes, in which the least significant predictors were removed (or refit with class independent coefficients when the difference in coefficient estimates across latent classes did not approach significance). At each step, we redetermined the corresponding optimal number of latent classes until there was no improvement in BIC (for additional details, see the Appendix).
The final model also minimized the consistent Akaike information criterion (AIC) (Bozdogan 1987), but the analysis indicated that minimization of AIC (Akaike 1974) and AIC3 (Bozdogan 1994) would require much more complicated models (at least 17 latent classes). mated VIFs do not exceed 3. 5 (still substantially below the benchmark of 5, which is an indication of high multicollinearity). Effect of extremes. We also calculated the Cook distance that corresponded to each residual. The distribution of these influence values is not significantly correlated with the size of the dependent variable (rank correlation = –. 05, p = . 557; raw correlation = –. 001, p = . 882), and the occurrence of a Cook distance >. 5 (which happens only 2% of the time, less than expected in the classical case) is only marginally correlated with the absolute size of the dependent variable (rank correlation = . 015, p = . 104). The Best Scientific Model The model that minimized BIC is the 14-class model that Table 3 summarizes. Overall, it accounts for 95% of the change in total business share of wallet, but within the largest latent class (50% of households), the R-square is only 63%, the third lowest among all latent classes.
It is difficult to classify each case accurately into the appropriate latent class. A case represents an observed change in a household’s total business share of wallet (along with the concomitant covariates and predictors for that household). The model makes classification errors with an estimated probability of 29. 7%, and the proportional reduction in the entropy of classification is 70. 2% when the model’s posterior probabilities are used rather than the marginal probabilities of each latent class (Kamakura and Wedel 1995).
For Class 1, the coefficient of the randomerror effect (which has a mean of zero) is much larger than any of the other covariate effects, so the estimate that 50% of cases (and 50% of households) belong to this class is based primarily on the large estimated variance of the random effect. These results indicate that, in many cases, it may be difficult to identify the most appropriate segment for an individual household. This is to be expected for a random effects model, and this uncertainty is a function of the natural heterogeneity among households.
Reducing the number of segments can also improve these classification statistics, but such a reduction should be done only after fitting the best scientific model for segmentation, which typically includes segments that may be difficult to recognize. A manager should focus on the larger, more identifiable segments. Nevertheless, it is the more complex model, which may include managerially irrelevant segments, that provides the most accurate way of identifying segments for which targeted corporate efforts would be most profitable and the best framework for a rigorous examination of the hypotheses under study.
Model Fit Inferences made from linear latent class models are asymptotically valid under relatively general conditions and allow for considerable departures from normality (Satorra 2002). However, we also checked the validity of the model in several ways. Overall, the residual analyses and other model diagnostics indicate that there are no serious problems with model fit. Residual diagnostics. In the final model, there is no significant serial correlation in the household residuals at Lag 1 and Lag 2 (in each case, p > . ). The nominal serial correlations indicate that less than one-tenth of 1% of the variance in residuals can be related to autocorrelation. This could be due to several factors, including the broad selection of candidate predictors, the differenced form of the dependent variable, and the model’s facility (through segmentation and random effects) to accommodate longitudinal and cross-sectional heterogeneity effectively. We also tested stationarity over time by performing a one-way analysis of variance of residuals by year.
The results indicate that there are no significant differences in average residual by year (p = . 63), and this is true even when the analysis is restricted to residuals from annual changes in share of wallet that are two or more years from the household’s baseline (p = . 71). These analyses also support homoskedasticity of residuals across years. Finally, the plot of residuals versus predicted values does not suggest that there are any problems with the assumption that errors have a constant mean of zero across prediction levels.
Multicollinearity. For the coefficients that are related to H1–H7, the estimated variance inflation factors (VIFs) were always less than 2 across segments. The estimated VIFs for the structural coefficients of variables that describe account activity (TB_SOWt – 1, MIt – 1, and MOt – 1) are larger, presumably because these variables are also used as covariates for latent class membership. Even in this latter case, esti- Profiles of the Primary Latent Classes
Table 3 describes the profiles in terms of the dependent variable, change in TB_SOW (change between times t and t – 1), the contemporaneous change in satisfaction, and other variables measured in initial period (t – 1). As Table 3 shows, the first two latent classes are similar to each other and unique among the 14 customer segments in several ways: 74 / Journal of Marketing, January 2007 TABLE 3 The Best Scientific Model: Class Sizes, R-Square, and Latent Class Profiles Averages 1 063 50. 0 50. 0 025 03. 5 051 072 014 014 050 054 051 088 05. 8 076 051 100 021 045 013 057 036 043 087 06. 084 020 069 048 028 015 056 043 048 085 06. 0 052 017 070 038 029 017 056 059 053 089 06. 0 011 048 262 031 031 015 056 047 049 085 05. 9 038 018 110 040 026 020 056 054 055 089 05. 8 001 048 285 032 035 014 056 063 055 088 05. 9 045 056 312 032 029 013 014 015 017 016 014 014 015 056 056 052 086 05. 9 046 042 163 033 030 072 070 066 066 060 070 070 052 050 048 048 048 050 050 048 066 018 014 056 044 047 087 05. 8 032 021 099 036 034 03. 6 03. 4 03. 3 03. 4 03. 2 03. 4 03. 4 03. 4 3. 5 51 70 13 15 53 48 48 87 5. 8 72 37 86 27 40 020 –13 000 –29 000 002 0–2 –35 18 0–7 3. 049 067 015 016 054 053 051 087 5. 8 011 041 148 029 032 100 12. 1 18. 1 081 05. 0 02. 3 065 04. 8 04. 4 096 04. 7 02. 8 041 04. 4 05. 8 025 03. 5 05. 6 065 03. 3 01. 2 100 02. 9 04. 3 98 2. 7 1. 1 095 2. 3 0. 9 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 100 1. 9 0. 8 018 3. 5 051 069 015 015 052 050 049 087 5. 9 080 047 084 020 048 13 066 1. 9 2. 6 000 3. 5 052 070 013 015 051 058 050 089 5. 9 094 072 210 023 046 14 098 0. 5 0. 2 002 3. 4 050 066 015 017 052 054 051 087 5. 9 044 040 149 021 045 Overall 095 100 100 002 3. 4 050 068 015 015 055 050 050 087 5. 9 050 036 147 034 033
Class R2 Percentage of cases Percentage of household types Change in TB_SOW (%SOWt – %SOWt – 1) Initial satisfaction (1–4, 4 is the highest) Change in satisfaction (Conditional percentile, %) Percentage with SAT = 3 or 4 and no change Percentage for whom satisfaction decreased Percentage for whom satisfaction increased Age (years) Income (percentile, %) Education (percentile, %) Sought professional advice (%) Length of relationship (years) Initial TB_SOW (%) Money-out ($1,000) Money-in ($1,000) Percentage with only money-in (Money-out/Total-business) ? 00% Customer Satisfaction and Share of Wallet / 75 Notes: Change in TB_SOW is the dependent variable; the predictors are in bold, and other variables are in italics; change in TB_SOW and change in satisfaction are contemporaneous; and all other variables are measured at the initial period (time t – 1).
In the case of the variable “percentage with only money-in,” we used an indicator to indicate when all household accounts were money-in (at baseline). An average change in satisfaction at the 51st conditional percentile indicates that, on average, these households had a change in satisfaction that was better than or equal to that of 51% of the households that started out at the same satisfaction level. They are the largest segments (Class 1: 50% of cases and households; Class 2: 12% of observations and 18% of households); •They have high initial satisfaction (Class 1 is the third highest, and Class 2 is the highest): extremely satisfied = 56% and 60% for Classes 1 and 2, respectively, and somewhat satisfied = 39% and 31%, respectively; •They remain at high levels of satisfaction: In each class, 72% of households were initially at one of the two highest levels of satisfaction and remained at precisely the same level during the next period (this is the highest level of high unchanged satisfaction among all classes); and •They have large average values of total business share of wallet with a primary institution: 76% and 84% for Classes 1 and 2, respectively.
However, the two largest classes also differ dramatically in terms of demographic characteristics and the type of business they conduct with their primary institutions: •Class 1 has the lowest average age (50), and Class 2 has the highest average age (57); •In Class 1, education is slightly above average (64% with some college), and Class 2 has the lowest average education (51% with some college); •In Class 1, the average income is slightly above the median (54th percentile), and Class 2 has the lowest average among all classes (36th percentile); •In Class 1, the tenure of the relationship with the primary institution is just below the average among all classes (5. 8 years), and Class 2 has the longest average tenure among classes (6. 1 years); and •Class 1 has the largest percentage of total business in the money-out category among classes, representing more than 1% of households (45% money-out), and Class 2 has the second-lowest percentage of money-out business among all classes (28%). all household transactions (of the last period) were moneyin.
As Table 4 shows, the other important predictors were income, tenure, the conditional percentile of change in satisfaction, and the initial satisfaction level. Tested across all classes, all predictors have significantly nonzero coefficients (p < . 0001) that are also significantly different across classes (p < . 0001). Brand (the actual financial institution) did not have any significant incremental value for predicting the change in total business share of wallet, and therefore we did not include it in these models. In this discussion of predictor effects, we refer to the actual average change in total business share of wallet (TB_SOWt – TB_SOWt – 1) in which each term is expressed as a percentage.
This is the difference between successive values of share of wallet, so even though it is also expressed in units of percent, it does not actually represent the percentage change in share of wallet relative to the actual baseline level of share of wallet. Effects of Last Period’s Business Type and Dollar Amount The last period’s total business share of wallet (TB_SOWt – 1) has a negative coefficient in every class, indicating that, on average, customers tend to make smaller positive or even negative adjustments to TB_SOW when it is already at higher levels, all else being equal. In contrast, the dollar level for money-in and money-out can have either a positive or a negative impact, depending on the latent class, but it always has an impact of less than . 1% on total business share of wallet per thousand dollar increase in level.
Similarly, the coefficient of the indicator for whether all business consists of money-in transactions can also be negative or positive. The largest coefficient estimate is in the largest latent class (Class 1), but even here, the effect is an average reduction of only 2% in the in total business share of wallet for households in which all transactions are money-in relative to households in which there is also money-out business. Nevertheless, the coefficients of these predictors (and the others we discuss subsequently) are highly significant and significantly different across classes (for both tests on each predictor, p < . 0001). Predictor Significance in the Latent Class Regressions
Three covariates used to determine the latent class were also of preeminent importance as predictors (TB_SOWt – 1, MIt – 1, and MOt – 1), along with the indicator for whether TABLE 4 Latent Class Regression Coefficients for Predictors Representing Satisfaction and Satisfaction Moderators in Classes That Represent at Least 4% of Either Cases or Household Types 1 Class R2 Percentage of cases Percentage of household types Predictor Coefficients Initial satisfaction (1–4, 4 is the highest) Change in satisfaction (50% change in conditional percentile) Income (percentile, %) Length of relationship (years) 63 50 50 02. 0 02. 7 –2. 9 0–. 2 2 100 012 018 0. 0 0. 0 –. 0 0. 0 3 81 05 02 000. 9 005. 1 –10. 1 000. 6 4 65 05 04 01. 0 00. 6 –1. 0 0–. 3 5 96 05 03 0. 9 2. 1 0. 5 0. 6 41 04 06 . 1 . 1 . 1 . 0 7 25 04 06 –. 1 00. 8 –2. 0 00. 5 9 100 003 004 0. 0 0. 0 0. 4 –. 0 Notes: Each coefficient represents change in TB_SOW (%SOWt – %SOWt – 1) per unit change in predictor, all else being equal. For change in conditional percentile of satisfaction, one unit change in this predictor represents a comparison between the third and the first quartiles of the distribution of annual changes in satisfaction among households that started at the same satisfaction level. All coefficients are significantly nonzero and significantly different across classes (for each test, p < . 0001). 76 / Journal of Marketing, January 2007 Results
The Effect of Change in Satisfaction (H1 and H2) Remarkably, among all the predictors, only the conditional percentile of change in satisfaction has a nearly consistent positive coefficient in each regression (Table 4), in support of H1. The only exception is Class 11 (not shown in Table 4), which represents approximately 2% of the observed changes in profiles and represents less than 1% of all households; yet even in this case, it is not significantly negative (the one-sided p value is . 45), representing less than onetenth of 1% average change in total business share of wallet, even for households that undergo the highest possible percentile of change in satisfaction. In the largest latent class (50% of observations and households), total business share of wallet increases by an average of 2. % per 50-percentile increase in satisfaction (relative to customers who started at the same satisfaction level). Nevertheless, as Table 4 shows, among the other latent classes that each represent at least 4% of households (Classes 2, 4, 6, and 7), the increases in total business share of wallet are less than 1% per 50percentile increase in satisfaction, and with the exception of Class 1, the average increase per household is only . 3% per 50-percentile increase in satisfaction. These changes assume that adjustments for other household characteristics (e. g. , type and level of business, tenure, income, and initial satisfaction level) have been made.
These results confirm a significant and positive, though somewhat modest, relationship between change in satisfaction and the concomitant change in total business share of wallet. This relationship differs by latent class and baseline satisfaction level, but it is strongest in the largest class (50% of households). Among the four classes that represent at least 4% of households, the largest class is characterized by the second-largest average volume of money-out business ($51,000) and the largest proportion (45%) of money-out dollars as a proportion of total business; thus, these are the types of customers who generate a large share of a financial institution’s profits.
After correcting for other variables in the model, including the initial satisfaction level, the best model posits a linear relationship per unit change in conditional percentile within latent class. However, this is not a linear relationship relative to the Likert scale, and it is not a constant linear relationship in percentile units across latent classes (p < . 0001). Furthermore, this within-class relationship requires an adjustment for initial satisfaction level. Because satisfaction is not measured on a ratio scale, its coefficient is interpreted as the parameter needed to calculate a new intercept on the basis of initial satisfaction ([original segment intercept + segment coefficient] ? [baseline satisfaction on the Likert scale]), which changes by segment.
In this way, it represents a segment-specific coefficient that provides a new anchor point for how share of wallet changes with each baseline satisfaction level, and this adjustment changes in an approximately linear way relative to the Likert scale (after we correct for change in satisfaction on a conditional percentile scale and for other moderating and structural variables). In the largest latent class and in all other classes except three (of which only Class 7 is large enough to be in Table 4), total business share of wallet also increases per increased level of initial satisfaction. These adjustments are modest (always less than 4% per Likert point). In the largest latent class, the coefficient represents an average increase of 2% per Likert point. In summary, the results are consistent with H2; we find a positive relationship between changes in share of wallet and changes in satisfaction that differs by customer segment and also depends on the baseline satisfaction level.
Moderators for the Effects of Change in Satisfaction (H3–H7) We tested the variables referred to in the seven hypotheses for incremental value in the model. Initially, we considered all these variables candidates, and we eliminated each in turn only if a better scientific model (lower BIC) could be obtained by doing so. In each case, we tested the effects of each variable after correcting for the effects of the other variables that are in the final (best scientific) model. H3. Overall, there is no evidence that age is a positive moderator. The age of the head of the household does not seem to have any significant incremental value (p = . 18). Among the four largest latent classes (Classes 1, 2, 6, and 7, representing 50%, 18%, 6%, nd 6% of households, respectively), change in satisfaction has the strongest effect in Class 1, in which the head of the household tends to be an average of at least five years younger. Thus, H3 is not supported. H4. Income is an important predictor in the final model and thus is significant and significantly different across classes (in both cases, p < . 0001). It has a negative coefficient in 9 of the 14 latent classes, and these 9 classes represent 86% of all households. Its effects, however, are modest. Its largest negative impact is in Class 1, in which there is a 1. 7% average decrease in total business share of wallet per 50-percentile increase in income, conditional on fixed levels of change in satisfaction and other household characteristics.
These results support H4, that income tends to moderate the relationship between changes in satisfaction and changes in total business share of wallet negatively. H5. Education is not a predictor in the best model and does not have significant incremental value in this model (p = . 74). There is a high correlation between income and education (r = . 987, p < . 0001, in which both variables are measured in terms of percentiles), so it can be used as a proxy for income; as such, it would be a negative moderator (as H5 posited), but income seems to be more directly related to changes in total business share of wallet. H6. The indicator for whether financial advisory services were used was not in the final model and did not have any incremental value when we added it (p = . 29).
Therefore, there is no support for H6 regarding the effects of expertise. However, the variable we used here indicates only whether a customer used advisory services and provides only limited and hypothetical information about the actual moderating effects of customer expertise. Customer Satisfaction and Share of Wallet / 77 H7. Length of relationship (tenure) with the financial institution was a significant predictor in the final model and had significantly different effects across classes (in both tests, p < . 0001). Its coefficient is negative in Class 1, in which there is an average decrease of . 2% in total business share of wallet per year of tenure.
It is never greater than its value in Class 3, which represents 2% of households and in which there is an average increase of . 6% in total business share of wallet per year. Thus, its overall effect is modest; the average effect per household is –. 08% per year. The coefficient is negative in only 4 of the 14 latent classes, but these 4 classes represent 60% of households. Thus, there is strong empirical support for the significance of this variable, and though its effects are modest, it tends to be a negative moderator (as hypothesized). General Discussion and Conclusions Our analysis advances the empirical research on the intuitive relationship between customer satisfaction and business outcomes in two key ways.
First, our findings indicate that changes in satisfaction are positively and nonlinearly related to the share of wallet a customer allocates to a particular service provider over time; specifically, the initial satisfaction level and the conditional percentile of change in satisfaction significantly correspond to changes in share of wallet. Second, the findings suggest that the relationship between satisfaction and share of wallet is moderated by both demographic and situational customer characteristics. In particular, income and length of relationship are significant predictors in the model. Both income and length of relationship negatively moderated the relationship between changes in satisfaction and share of wallet.
This corresponds to similar findings regarding the relationships between satisfaction and repurchase intention and between satisfaction and retention (Mittal and Kamakura 2001). The key implication is that managers should not simply strive to improve reported satisfaction levels without an understanding of the relationship to customers’ share-ofwallet allocations. Given that both the initial satisfaction level and the conditional percentile of change in satisfaction are significantly associated with changes in share of wallet, it is critical that managers design their efforts to improve satisfaction so that customers reach the satisfaction levels that correspond to higher share-of-wallet levels.
This may require a reevaluation of the means with which managers currently measure the potential return on investment from improvement efforts aimed at changing customer behavior through improved customer satisfaction, particularly if cross-sectional analyses are currently used. Cross-sectional (as opposed to longitudinal) examinations of the relationship between customer satisfaction and customer behavior may be unable to identify adequately the roles of both baseline satisfaction levels and change in satisfaction on customers’ share-of-wallet allocations. Furthermore, simply treating all customers as homogeneous has the potential to misrepresent the relationship between satisfaction and share of wallet. Therefore, it is mportant that the level of influence of various customer segments on share of wallet be uncovered so that resources can be appropriately allocated to those areas, thus providing the greatest impact. For example, in this study, there is an interesting contrast between the households in the two largest classes; households in Class 1 tend to be clients with more income and a larger volume of money-out business than clients in Class 2, and they are also more responsive to both higher baseline satisfaction levels and positive changes in satisfaction. The influence of satisfaction on customers’ share-ofwallet allocations to a bank has strategic implications for managers. As opposed to retention (i. e. the business relationship is on/off), the ability to manipulate share of wallet demonstrates that many, if not most, customers have relationships with multiple financial institutions rather than an exclusive/monogamous relationship with an individual institution. Therefore, customers are more likely to be aware of competitors’ offerings and to have some level of interaction with competing institutions. Knowledge and experience lower customers’ perceived risk (Rust, Zahorik, and Keiningham 1994). Consequently, changes in service levels that affect the level of customer satisfaction can more easily result in the inflow or outflow of money to the firm.
Given the increasingly polygamous loyalty that consumers hold toward firms/brands (Bennett and Rundle-Thiele 2005; Rust, Lemon, and Zeithaml 2004; Uncles, Dowling, and Hammond 2003; Uncles, Ehrenberg, and Hammond 1995), this issue is likely to transcend the banking industry. Limitatio
Delivering a high-quality product at a reasonable price is not enough anymore.
That’s why we have developed 5 beneficial guarantees that will make your experience with our service enjoyable, easy, and safe.
You have to be 100% sure of the quality of your product to give a money-back guarantee. This describes us perfectly. Make sure that this guarantee is totally transparent.
Read moreEach paper is composed from scratch, according to your instructions. It is then checked by our plagiarism-detection software. There is no gap where plagiarism could squeeze in.
Read moreThanks to our free revisions, there is no way for you to be unsatisfied. We will work on your paper until you are completely happy with the result.
Read moreYour email is safe, as we store it according to international data protection rules. Your bank details are secure, as we use only reliable payment systems.
Read moreBy sending us your money, you buy the service we provide. Check out our terms and conditions if you prefer business talks to be laid out in official language.
Read more